Philipp Bagus
lewrockwell.com
December 14, 2013
A paper currency system contains the seeds of its own destruction. The
temptation for the monopolist money producer to increase the money supply is
almost irresistible. In such a system with a constantly increasing money supply
and, as a consequence, constantly increasing prices, it does not make much sense
to save in cash to purchase assets later. A better strategy, given this senario,
is to go into debt to purchase assets and pay back the debts later with a
devalued currency. Moreover, it makes sense to purchase assets that can later be
pledged as collateral to obtain further bank loans. A paper money system leads
to excessive debt.
This is especially true of players that can expect that they will be bailed
out with newly produced money such as big businesses, banks, and the
government.
We are now in a situation that looks like a dead end for the paper money
system. After the last cycle, governments have bailed out malinvestments in the
private sector and boosted their public welfare spending. Deficits and debts
skyrocketed. Central banks printed money to buy public debts (or accept them as
collateral in loans to the banking system) in unprecedented amounts. Interest
rates were cut close to zero. Deficits remain large. No substantial real growth
is in sight. At the same time banking systems and other financial players sit on
large piles of public debt. A public default would immediately trigger the
bankruptcy of the banking sector. Raising interest rates to more realistic
levels or selling the assets purchased by
the central bank would put into jeopardy the solvency of the banking sector,
highly indebted companies, and the government. It looks like even the slowing
down of money printing (now called “QE tapering”) could trigger a bankruptcy
spiral. A drastic reduction of government spending and deficits does not seem
very likely either, given the incentives for politicians in democracies.
So will money printing be a constant with interest rates close to zero until
people lose their confidence in the paper currencies? Can the paper money system
be maintained or will we necessarily get a hyperinflation sooner or later?
There are at least seven possibilities:
1. Inflate. Governments and central banks can simply proceed
on the path of inflation and print all the money necessary to bail out the
banking system, governments, and other over-indebted agents. This will further
increase moral hazard. This option ultimately leads into hyperinflation, thereby
eradicating debts. Debtors profit, savers lose. The paper wealth that people
have saved over their life time will not be able to assure such a high standard
of living as envisioned.
2. Default on Entitlements. Governments can improve their
financial positions by simply not fulfilling their promises. Governments may,
for instance, drastically cut public pensions, social security and unemployment
benefits to eliminate deficits and pay down accumulated debts. Many
entitlements, that people have planned upon, will prove to be worthless.
3. Repudiate Debt. Governments can also default outright on
their debts. This leads to losses for banks and insurance companies that have
invested the savings of their clients in government bonds. The people see the
value of their mutual funds, investment funds, and insurance plummet thereby
revealing the already-occurred losses. The default of the government could lead
to the collapse of the banking system. The bankruptcy spiral of overindebted
agents would be an economic Armageddon. Therefore, politicians until now have
done everything to prevent this option from happening.
4. Financial Repression. Another way to get out of the debt
trap is financial
repression. Financial repression is a way of channeling more funds to the
government thereby facilitating public debt liquidation. Financial repression
may consist of legislation making investment alternatives less attractive or
more directly in regulation inducing investors to buy government bonds. Together
with real growth and spending cuts, financial repression may work to actually
reduce government debt loads.
5. Pay Off Debt. The problem of overindebtedness can also be
solved through fiscal measures. The idea is to eliminate debts of governments
and recapitalize banks through taxation. By reducing overindebtedness, the need
for the central bank to keep interest low and to continue printing money is
alleviated. The currency could be put on a sounder base again. To achieve this
purpose, the government expropriates wealth on a massive scale to pay back
government debts. The government simply increases existing tax rates or may
employ one-time confiscatory expropriations of wealth. It uses these receipts to
pay down its debts and recapitalize banks. Indeed the IMF has
recently proposed a one-time 10-percent wealth tax in Europe in order to
reduce the high levels of public debts. Large scale cuts in spending could also
be employed to pay off debts. After WWII, the US managed to reduce its
debt-to-GDP ratio from 130 percent in 1946 to 80 percent in 1952. However, it
seems unlikely that such a debt reduction through spending cuts could work
again. This time the US does not stand at the end of a successful war.
Government spending was cut in half from $118
billion in 1945 to $58 billion in 1947, mostly through cuts in military
spending. Similar spending cuts today do not seem likely without leading to
massive political resistance and bankruptcies of overindebted agents depending
on government spending.
6. Currency Reform. There is the option of a full-fledged
currency reform including a (partial) default on government debt. This option is
also very attractive if one wants to eliminate overindebtedness without engaging
in a strong price inflation. It is like pressing the reset button and continuing
with a paper money regime. Such a reform worked in Germany after the WWII (after
the last war financial repression was not an option) when the old paper money,
the Reichsmark, was substituted by a new paper money, the Deutsche Mark. In this
case, savers who hold large amounts of the old currency are heavily
expropriated, but debt loads for many people will decline.
7. Bail-in. There could be a bail-in amounting to a half-way
currency reform. In a bail-in, such as occurred in Cyprus, bank creditors
(savers) are converted into bank shareholders. Bank debts decrease and equity
increases. The money supply is reduced. A bail-in recapitalizes the banking
system, and eliminates bad debts at the same time. Equity may increase so much,
that a partial default on government bonds would not threaten the stability of
the banking system. Savers will suffer losses. For instance, people that
invested in life insurances that in turn bought bank liabilities or government
bonds will assume losses. As a result the overindebtedness of banks and
governments is reduced.
Any of the seven options, or combinations of two or more options, may lie
ahead. In any case they will reveal the
losses incurred in and end the wealth illusion. Basically, taxpayers,
savers, or currency users are exploited to reduce debts and put the currency on
a more stable basis. A one-time wealth tax, a currency reform or a bail-in are
not very popular policy options as they make losses brutally apparent at once.
The first option of inflation is much more popular with governments as it hides
the costs of the bail out of overindebted agents. However, there is the danger
that the inflation at some point gets out of control. And the monopolist money
producer does not want to spoil his privilege by a monetary meltdown. Before it
gets to the point of a runaway inflation, governments will increasingly ponder
the other options as these alternatives could enable a reset of the system.
Saturday, December 14, 2013
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment